Podchaser Logo
Home
Tim Harford, the Undercover Economist: Are we too ideological about privatisation?

Tim Harford, the Undercover Economist: Are we too ideological about privatisation?

Released Sunday, 19th May 2024
Good episode? Give it some love!
Tim Harford, the Undercover Economist: Are we too ideological about privatisation?

Tim Harford, the Undercover Economist: Are we too ideological about privatisation?

Tim Harford, the Undercover Economist: Are we too ideological about privatisation?

Tim Harford, the Undercover Economist: Are we too ideological about privatisation?

Sunday, 19th May 2024
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:01

This episode is brought to you by

0:03

Accenture. A better you starts with better

0:06

hydration. Accenture is on a mission to

0:08

inspire people to do what matters most.

0:10

Their proprietary ionization process transforms water from

0:13

any source into ionized alkaline water, providing

0:15

water that's 99.9% pure with a pH

0:17

of 9.5 or higher. Accenture

0:23

overachieving H2O, the number one

0:25

ionized alkaline water. Shop

0:27

now. When.

0:30

Was the last time I tucker Welsh? How

0:32

many national parks can I hadn't? Two weeks.

0:34

What about hotels? Wait A Erica. Manage my

0:36

spending on travel. When your questions about why

0:39

turn into questions about money, there's Erica the

0:41

virtual financial assistant to help you spend, save

0:43

and plants. Modern only from Bank of America.

0:45

What would you like? The power to do?

0:47

Erica is only available me English language. You

0:50

must download the latest version of the mobile

0:52

banking. I'm only them learn from it Mobile.

0:54

Devices Gortat may be recorded a monitored for quality. Assurance

0:56

message and data rates in additional told me it might make

0:58

of America and a member of the icy. When.

1:09

No matter what tasty choice you make, you'll

1:11

enjoy our everyday low prices. Plus, extra ways

1:13

to save, like digital coupons worth over $600

1:16

each week. You

1:18

can also save up to $1 off per gallon

1:20

at the pump with fuel points. More

1:22

savings and more inspiring flavors. The.

1:41

Hello Welcome to the rest is

1:43

money with me Robert Peston staff

1:46

will be back very soon process

1:48

but for today it's may not

1:50

quite all my own. The great

1:53

thing about this show is I

1:55

get some Meet my business and

1:57

economic heroes Fellow nerds. fellow

2:00

geeks, fellow nerds. And I'm absolutely

2:03

thrilled to be joined by Tim

2:05

Harford. A few years ago we

2:08

were colleagues at the BBC. I

2:10

mean from memory, the first time

2:12

we met was, or bet properly,

2:15

was when I came

2:17

on your amazing more or

2:19

less show to talk about

2:21

how many trillions of dollars

2:24

of British and sort

2:26

of government money across the world

2:28

had been allocated to propping up

2:30

the banks. Oh, those days. Those happy

2:32

days. Yes, exactly. What I

2:35

really remember, Robert, I remember two things.

2:37

One is that I once walked into

2:39

the PM studio when you were being

2:41

terribly insightful about something or other. I

2:43

forget exactly what. And I was wearing

2:45

a wet t-shirt because I had just

2:48

done the ice bucket challenge. And

2:50

I think you were polite enough not to mention

2:52

that I was just dripping over the microphone. And

2:54

then the last time we saw each other, you

2:56

gave me a great big hug. I hope this

2:58

interview is going to finish with a great

3:01

big hug. And the reason you gave

3:03

me a great big hug is I

3:05

think you were overwhelmed with emotion because

3:07

you had just sung Bohemian Rhapsody with

3:09

my local community choir, which is extremely

3:11

challenging and brave thing to do. And

3:13

you did a very good job. Maybe

3:15

not quite as good as the guitar solo, but you did a

3:17

wonderful job. And then you came off stage and I think I

3:19

was the first thing you saw

3:21

and you just grabbed onto me and held on for

3:24

dear life. It was a beautiful moment. I'd forgot that

3:26

you were sort of to blame.

3:28

I think

3:31

I have a nasty feeling it's still

3:34

available on YouTube, but I'm sure nobody will want to

3:36

find it. Just tell us a little bit. I've

3:39

entered the, or I've been in podcast world for a

3:41

bit. You're in the podcast world. I am. I am.

3:43

So my day job is undercover economist at the Financial

3:46

Times, write a column for the FT Magazine. How long

3:48

has that been going on for now? I mean, it

3:50

must be, is it 20 years? Very nearly 20, 18

3:52

years. Yeah. More than 18. Goodness me.

3:57

They'll sack me eventually. But I Also, yes.

4:00

I have a courthouse to have put

4:02

cause called Cautionary Tales with Tim Harford

4:04

which is all about things going terribly

4:06

wrong and also the lessons that we

4:08

should learn. and think fans of the

4:10

rest is money may like to know

4:12

that some of the stories are about

4:14

money. So we had a Aretha moan

4:16

about a spectacular ponzi scheme involving the

4:18

Cia except not really and a global

4:20

conspiracy except not really. an awful lot

4:22

of drugs are they really really were

4:24

involved that walk on par from Donald

4:26

Trump. It is hop see astonishing. So

4:28

am courses house with Tim Harford. Haven't

4:30

noticed some podcasting some isn't it now

4:32

so he about things going wrong that's

4:35

kick off. We've had a number of

4:37

questions and we to do blah jesus

4:39

discussions that and we had a number

4:41

of listeners questions on G D P

4:43

when I was at the Bbc and

4:45

I still do this on my Tv

4:47

you can't ever just say Gdp an

4:50

Arab news report because I sleep with

4:52

a Bbc poll people on this almost

4:54

nobody knows what Gdp is as so

4:56

I was at the come up with

4:58

a power fries and so. I would

5:00

always say Gdp all national income the

5:03

value of already we produce staccato. Say

5:05

I'm not actually hundred percent certain that

5:07

even that makes much sense to people

5:10

know about advice that cystic of we

5:12

which olds and he says why to

5:14

economists talk about grows, why is it

5:16

important? What does he do Should we

5:19

be happy with the status quo? So

5:21

when economists talk about growth say are

5:23

talking about growth in this thing Gdp

5:26

gross domestic. Product. And the

5:28

right with an endless hold on

5:30

Gdp per second is fascinating. Seats

5:32

weird is weird. It is basically

5:34

saying we're going to just measure

5:36

the economy. We're going to miss

5:38

all the stuff. Everything. So everything

5:40

from people sweeping floors, to people

5:42

making calls, to people performing bowel

5:44

cancer surgery to podcast advertising that

5:46

which was would just and will

5:48

add it all up in some

5:50

way. And I'm going to interrupt

5:53

just one second because column people

5:55

including my sister will be named.

5:57

Probably shouting if I point this out. There are quite

5:59

important things. One in the economy that are

6:01

measured like you know. she does a lot of

6:03

unpaid caring for my mother which is obviously valuable

6:05

and that is not included in Gdp. Yeah no

6:07

you sleeping with holes is included in Gdp if

6:10

you get paid to see the floor. but if

6:12

you don't get paid foods or it doesn't getting

6:14

sued, well it depends exactly to have a different

6:16

attempts to measure these things. But yeah but I

6:18

think that's how did I hear of when I

6:20

combo it's not, it's not to him so it

6:22

is this magnificent bonkers com I to mentioned yet

6:25

to just add everything up. To

6:27

say okay how much is all of that

6:29

And a hundred years ago Tdp was was

6:31

not invented. There was no such thing as

6:33

if you had asked person in the street

6:35

know how is the economy doing the quest

6:37

is kind of into haven't I mean you

6:39

could say well you can you find a

6:42

job or knows his stuff. Too expensive but

6:44

Gdp is. It is a study. Weird seeing

6:46

something we should we should a goes up

6:48

from the saw. An excellent lucky one. Ah

6:50

the classic. There are cultural factors here. One

6:52

of things I've always been struck by his

6:54

we as a nation ah, obsessed with. Gdp,

6:56

I leaves the bullet zones. You

6:59

know, if as a recession, which

7:01

is two successive courses of shrinking

7:03

Gdp, it's a lot. was. we've

7:05

got a question from an accessory

7:07

a young about that, which is

7:09

she's a wise Gdp. still a

7:11

measure of policy political success. But

7:13

the reason I'm so looking at

7:15

this sort of national obsession is

7:18

because of I Look at America.

7:20

they are much more traditionally interested

7:22

in employments. yeah, unemployment, still more

7:24

Isis, which seems sort of actually

7:26

intuitively. More sensible because the points about

7:28

the economy is it should be to make

7:30

a prosperous and therefore what the things you

7:33

wouldn't we should be solely more is today

7:35

days at he got a job, what you

7:37

being paid and what semi to prices Yara

7:39

I'd makes more sense to Miami. Gdp is

7:41

of course connected towards those things but it

7:44

is a slightly abstract way of going about

7:46

it. And I'm Anna Katrina Young's question is

7:48

good says he says why why is Tdp

7:50

still a measure of policy political success? You're

7:53

right. Well but it does lead to news

7:55

puts his I'm not sure. that is

7:57

is such measures policy success we

7:59

sink the policies of the current government,

8:01

whether people think they're good or

8:03

bad. They're clearly not targeted at maximising

8:05

GDP. So Brexit was explicitly, this is

8:07

not about GDP, it's not about the

8:09

economy, it's about taking back control. I

8:12

do sort of have to take effect

8:14

to what was actually said at the

8:16

time. And let's be clear,

8:19

significant leaders of

8:22

the two campaigns to take us

8:24

out of the EU did say

8:26

it would make us richer. It

8:28

was always economic nonsense to claim

8:31

it was going to make us richer. Or an

8:33

ITV night after night said it's going to make

8:35

us poorer. There may be other reasons why you

8:37

want to leave the EU, but for goodness sake,

8:39

don't vote to leave the EU if you think

8:41

you're going to be richer as a result. They

8:44

did claim that. Losing argument though, because nobody cared.

8:46

Losing argument. But I mean, other examples, if you

8:48

wanted more GDP, you'd build more houses. If you

8:50

wanted more GDP, you'd have more immigrants. I'm not

8:52

saying we should build more houses, we should have

8:54

more immigrants. Well, I mean, we could discuss whether

8:56

I could say that. But the point is those

8:59

things would obviously increase GDP

9:02

and the government is not arguing

9:04

for them, broadly speaking, the opposition is not

9:06

arguing for them. So I'm not sure it's

9:08

really true that GDP is the policy target

9:10

or whatever has been. And do you think

9:13

that it's that GDP per

9:15

head has ever

9:18

been actually more importantly, should

9:20

be a sensible policy target? Because

9:22

the point about GDP per head

9:25

is in theory, it

9:27

should tell us something about what

9:29

we can pay everybody, what resources

9:31

are available to fund public services

9:33

that are then a benefit to

9:36

individuals. It sort of should give

9:38

you a slightly better

9:40

measure of what we can sort of

9:42

afford. I mean, do you think that's

9:44

right? Yeah, if GDP grows, it's easier

9:46

to pay the bills,

9:48

it's easier to fund public services,

9:50

it's easier to pay debt. If

9:52

GDP per person grows, then that's

9:54

connected in a fairly direct way

9:56

with living standards with materially

9:59

what people can afford. I think one

10:01

of the reasons why the UK is obsessed

10:03

with GDP and trying to get growth in

10:05

GDP up is because we haven't had much

10:07

growth in GDP. Just to remind people, we've

10:09

been a basically a period of very

10:12

lackluster growth since about 2008, since the financial crash

10:14

we were just talking about. 92 to 2007 growth

10:16

was more or less 3% a year. It's been

10:18

nearer 1% a year since

10:23

then. So the collapse in GDP growth has

10:25

been really astonishing. Yeah, and that difference of

10:27

2% points a year for 15 years,

10:30

getting on for 20 years, that really adds

10:33

up. We could be a quarter richer or

10:35

a third richer. If you had a third

10:37

more money in your pocket, you would notice.

10:39

But it all sounds very abstract. What does

10:41

it basically look like? Well, at the moment,

10:43

taxes are high in the UK and public

10:45

services are, according to most people's perceptions, pretty

10:48

poor. We're worried about everything from

10:50

potholes to transport to the NHS,

10:52

but we're also having

10:54

a big debt burden and we're still running

10:56

a deficit, and yet taxes are high. That's

10:58

really what low GDP growth looks

11:01

like. If GDP growth was higher, there might

11:03

be all kinds of problems connected with that.

11:05

It would just be easier to cut

11:08

taxes while at the same time improving public services.

11:10

That's what we've not been in a position to

11:12

do for 15 years. You, like

11:14

me, probably talked to an economist

11:16

called Richard Layard from time to

11:18

time. He says... That's Lord Layard,

11:20

you and me. He

11:23

doesn't insist on it yet. Professor

11:26

Layard. Anyway, Richard says that we

11:28

should be measuring something else entirely,

11:31

which is how we feel, our happiness. And

11:34

that in the end, GDP

11:37

is about, we

11:39

think, the underpinnings of

11:42

a stable, coherent, happy

11:44

society. Actually, if you

11:47

look across the world, the

11:49

connection just between GDP growth and

11:51

happiness is not a particularly... Plainly

11:55

very poor countries are

11:57

often very miserable, but once you reach...

12:00

a certain level of prosperity,

12:02

the rate of growth doesn't

12:04

seem to be that directly

12:06

related to how happy

12:08

you feel. So there are quite a

12:10

lot of rich countries in Europe which

12:12

appear to be happier countries than a

12:14

country like the US where the

12:16

growth is much faster. So can

12:19

we measure happiness in any kind of scientific

12:21

way in your view? And

12:23

should we, should governments put more

12:25

emphasis on happiness rather

12:27

than this aggregate

12:29

level of how much we

12:31

produce, GDP? So it's such an interesting set

12:33

of questions that emerges from this. I mean,

12:35

first of all, yeah, of course you can

12:37

measure happiness. It's very simple. You ask people

12:39

how they're feeling. There are different ways to

12:41

do it. You can ask people how they

12:43

felt about the things they did in their

12:45

day, or you could just say, well, how

12:47

are things going for you overall? And you

12:50

get pretty sensible, unsurprising results. I mean, I

12:52

wouldn't put too much weight on them. Can

12:54

you imagine measuring national income by going to

12:56

a sample of 10,000 people and

12:58

asking each of them, how rich

13:00

are you these days on a scale of one

13:02

to 10? And people would say, well, I'm a six

13:04

or I'm an eight. It's

13:06

not good that you'd get a coherent answer,

13:09

10 years on, 20 years on, 100 years

13:11

on, the definition

13:13

of what rich means is going

13:15

to change. But that is how we measure happiness. We

13:17

say, how satisfied are you with

13:19

your life or how happy are you? So I'm

13:22

not that excited by the finding that

13:24

happiness is not super correlated with, with

13:26

say GDP, but I do think it's

13:28

very useful to measure happiness. I think

13:30

we should be measuring all kinds of

13:32

things. It's crazy to imagine that there'd

13:35

be this one policy indicator that you could

13:37

measure that would tell you how to run

13:39

the country or what to target. We need

13:41

to measure jobs. We need to measure prices.

13:44

We need to measure how well the

13:46

transport system is functioning. We need to

13:48

measure sewage discharges. We need to measure

13:50

NHS waiting lists and sure also measure

13:52

happiness. And for me, the most interesting

13:54

stuff that's come out of Lord Layard's

13:56

work and the work of other happiness

14:00

related directly to treatment for

14:02

mental distress. So cognitive behavioral

14:04

therapy, for example. Talking

14:06

therapy is a treatment for people who are

14:08

suffering periods of mental distress. Does it work?

14:10

Looks like it probably does. That's really useful.

14:13

To say, oh, the country as a

14:15

whole is an 8.2. No harm in

14:17

gathering the data, but I don't think

14:19

it's going to revolutionize anything. And broadly,

14:21

what you learn about the macro economy

14:23

is, well, people don't like inequality. People

14:25

don't like being jobless. People

14:28

would rather have some money than less

14:30

money. People don't like being ill. I mean,

14:32

these are not- So I think we could sort of

14:34

summarize that as insecurity definitely

14:37

makes people feel less happy.

14:39

And indeed, if you look

14:41

at the kind

14:43

of insecurity that we

14:45

all faced during COVID,

14:47

it undoubtedly also contributed

14:49

to a very

14:52

significant rise in mental ill

14:54

health. So plainly, growth matters,

14:56

creating a sense of direction

14:59

and confidence in where we're

15:01

going economically, plainly very

15:03

important. And to loop all the way back

15:05

to Rich Alderton's original question, which we have

15:07

not quite answered, which is why do economists

15:10

talk about growth? Can't we ever be happy

15:12

with the status quo? I mean, I think

15:14

there's clearly nothing wrong with this slightly weird

15:17

abstract thing called the economy growing. That's fine.

15:19

It's kind of a natural process. People get

15:21

smarter. They develop new things. Education gets better.

15:23

Humanity makes progress. But behind

15:25

the question when this is asked is

15:28

a concern about the environment. We're worried

15:30

about the consumption of natural resources. We're

15:32

worried about CO2 emissions. And my

15:34

argument there would be, well, just as we need

15:36

to measure this stuff directly when we're talking about

15:38

happiness, or we need to measure jobs or inflation

15:40

directly when we're talking about the economy, when we're

15:43

talking about the environment, we need to measure environmental

15:45

damage directly. And if you want to make things

15:47

better, you need direct policies to target environmental damage,

15:49

rather than just some vague sense of if only

15:51

we could stop growing, the environment would be okay.

15:53

Well, it wouldn't. And by the way, in the

15:55

UK, we kind of have achieved the goal of

15:58

stopping growing for a while and it's not. been

16:00

very pleasant. So I think you and I probably

16:02

agree that GDP is important, but it's too crude

16:04

a measure of success.

16:07

I should also mention Andrew Wilson, what does

16:09

it talk about happiness? Which we have. We

16:11

have. It's a good question, Andrew. But there

16:13

is a sort of interesting related question here

16:15

from Ola Kelly. And she points out, I

16:17

mean, I read a very interesting piece about

16:20

this actually in The Economist recently, how

16:23

Gen Z, particularly in the

16:25

States, is doing a lot

16:28

better than I think they probably think

16:30

and most people think. I mean, broadly, if

16:32

you meet any young people, what they do

16:34

is they moan that the older generation has

16:36

destroyed everything for them, mucked it up. It's

16:38

all our fault. I've put my hands up.

16:40

Yeah, it definitely is all my fault that

16:42

so many young people aren't

16:45

having such a great time. Sorry

16:47

about that. But statistically, it looks

16:49

like Gen Z, those are people,

16:52

if you like these naming conventions, these are people born between

16:54

1997 and 2013. It looks as though actually that generation in

16:59

terms of employment and income

17:02

is doing pretty well. In fact, I think the

17:04

argument of The Economist was they're

17:07

doing better than pretty much

17:09

every preceding generation, including

17:12

I'm a boomer. I don't think you are a baby boomer. I

17:14

imagine you're a... You look so young, Robert. I'm Gen X. I

17:17

was going to accuse you of being an

17:19

exer. I'm 50 years old, 50 years old

17:21

and proud. But anyway, I'm a late boomer

17:23

and most people think everything is our fault.

17:26

But apparently, the Gen Z, who are apparently

17:28

known as Zoomers, are doing pretty well. And

17:30

there is evidence in America that they're doing

17:32

pretty well. I suppose two things follow from

17:34

that. Why are they doing well in America?

17:36

You've never sounded more like a grandfather, Robert.

17:38

That's fantastic. I wish I was,

17:40

Robert. But if I haven't yet fulfilled that, very

17:42

important ambition. Anyway, the question is, why

17:45

are Zoomers doing well in America?

17:47

Are Zoomers doing okay in the

17:49

UK? I think

17:52

probably not doing as well in the UK, but you have

17:54

a go at it first. Very

17:56

first thing to say, we're talking about a

17:58

group of people who are between the ages

18:00

of 11 and 27. And so

18:02

to ask how they're doing economically, you know,

18:04

it's pretty early days, half of them haven't

18:07

even left school. So let's look at that

18:09

22 to 7 cohort. How

18:11

are they doing? I think the reason people

18:14

assume that Gen Z or Gen Z must be

18:16

doing badly is because I think the scars of

18:18

the financial crisis are still with us. Under the

18:20

scars of Covid. Yes, but we're used to this

18:22

idea that everything kind of went to hell in

18:24

a handcart about 15 years ago.

18:27

And it's been bad ever since. And

18:29

that is broadly true, sadly,

18:31

in the UK, less true

18:34

in the US. It comes back to this conversation

18:36

we're having about growth. I mean, it's not everything

18:38

but it does matter. The US has been growing

18:40

a lot more over the last 10, 15

18:42

years than the UK. And that just means that

18:45

the average person in the US is richer. And

18:47

they're going through a very strong period of growth

18:49

at the moment. And they've got an employment shortage

18:51

problem, a bit like we have. And so lots of

18:54

these young people not only have jobs,

18:56

but it's quite interesting. They're getting really large

18:58

pay rises when they've got a job. Yeah.

19:00

I mean, that's kind of the natural order

19:02

of things. We've had this experience for a

19:04

century or more of each generation is richer

19:06

than the previous generation. And I think the

19:08

millennials waking up and going, hang on, it's

19:10

not clear that we are richer than Gen

19:12

X. That was the shocking thing. That was

19:14

the exception. It was true. In the US, it's

19:16

kind of back to business as usual. And I

19:18

think less so in the UK. I mean, I

19:20

don't think we've got really good data,

19:23

but I've got some numbers in front of

19:25

me from the resolution foundation who do it.

19:27

They call it intergenerational audit. And they

19:30

say that millennials born in the

19:32

late eighties, and on average,

19:34

8% less at age 30

19:36

than members of Generation X born 10 years

19:38

prior. So they're looking at a slightly older

19:41

cohort, but I think that we see

19:43

a different pattern in the UK. I think it is important

19:45

to mention here, a sort of set

19:47

of statistics that are really troubling, which

19:49

is the significant rise.

19:52

I sort of alluded to

19:54

this general problem earlier, the

19:56

significant rise in mental ill

19:58

health among that younger. generation,

20:00

people in their early 20s, which

20:03

appears to be worse in the

20:05

UK than in other

20:07

similar countries. Again, I think

20:10

some of that will be related to a

20:12

lack of a sense of opportunity because of

20:14

low growth. Yeah. I

20:16

mean, it's really hard to measure. Some of it is

20:18

likely to be changes in conventions, but some of it

20:20

seems to be very real, real measures

20:22

of distress are arising. And yeah, and it's

20:25

not clear why, but I'm sure economic insecurity

20:27

is part of it. I mean, the pure

20:29

growth thing matters. So again, the Resolution Foundation,

20:31

they point out income growth. So this is for

20:33

everybody. This is average income growth. Income

20:35

growth in the US between 2007 and 2021, median household incomes grew

20:37

by 17%. So

20:42

if you were earning $20,000, now you're earning

20:44

$23,500. Nice

20:49

improvement. In the UK, 2%. So

20:52

if you're earning £20,000, you're basically still earning

20:54

£20,000. And against

20:56

that backdrop, of course, it's

20:58

harder for each generation to make progress.

21:00

And there's a related issue or a

21:02

related disparity, shall we say, between the

21:04

US and the UK, which

21:07

is they don't have the

21:09

kind of shortage we have in

21:11

this country of decent

21:14

housing. And prices

21:16

are not so far out of

21:18

the reach of younger people who

21:20

want to get on the housing

21:23

ladder. A sort of related issue

21:25

to the one about whether incomes

21:27

are growing is whether you've got

21:29

the opportunity to own a home. And

21:32

plainly, opportunities to own homes in this

21:35

country, in the UK, I mean,

21:38

they're inadequate. Yeah. It's almost

21:40

a uniquely British thing. I think it's

21:42

worth underlining what an exception the

21:44

UK is to much of the rest of the

21:46

developed world in terms of our constriction on house

21:49

building. Whether you like, whether you think it's a

21:51

brilliant idea, whether you think it's a terrible idea,

21:53

I think it's a terrible idea that we make

21:55

it so hard to build houses. It is unusual

21:58

In Japan, for example, very, very. To

22:00

build your house is in in the U

22:02

S much easier to build new house it's

22:04

there were few there were some cities are

22:06

it's hard San Francisco, it's hard but generally

22:08

was easy to build new houses and if

22:11

it's he's to build you houses. Whatever the

22:13

downsides of that fundamentally the cost of buying

22:15

a new house is basically the cost of

22:17

building a new house cause you know if

22:19

you've what some of us to buy a

22:21

house where you build them a house can't

22:23

happen in the Uk and I've I remember

22:25

meeting Caped Barca who had this review for

22:28

Blaze Government must beat beat he sounds and

22:30

maybe to as she was producing these these

22:32

estimates of how many houses we need spill

22:34

and governments keepsakes. Oh yeah yeah yeah, we

22:36

will build more houses or will let the

22:38

private sector build more houses or will provide

22:40

incentives to build houses and we fallen short

22:42

of Caped Baucus target fluid. He had a

22:44

problem. in the year two thousand houses were

22:47

already expensive in the a two thousand been

22:49

nearly a quarter of a century and this

22:51

has been getting worse and worse and worse

22:53

at a cost that plays in hugely to

22:55

intergenerational problems. Because if you feel old enough

22:57

to bought a house in the early nineteen

22:59

nineties, than. Your phone and if you're

23:01

not been you know know it is.

23:03

As you point out, one of the

23:05

most stock sources of inequality in this

23:07

case intergenerational the ah Anna and then

23:09

between people of the same generation. If

23:12

your parents bought a house and then

23:14

when they die they can give you

23:16

the house or they can maybe removes

23:18

the house in and help you out.

23:20

it starts to introduce a week is

23:22

a convenience. Talk about all. This is

23:24

what generates a doing. This is what

23:26

the millennials are doing. This is what

23:28

Gens added doing but actually am. often

23:30

you got very privileged members

23:32

of each generation and very

23:34

underprivileged members of each generation

23:36

and the housing market helps

23:38

to transmit that privilege down

23:40

the generations i mean it

23:42

is certainly the case that

23:44

we don't yet understand the

23:47

social consequences of this extraordinary

23:49

generational inequality in asset ownership

23:51

and we would bow to

23:53

embark on this cycle great

23:55

transfer of wealth from older

23:57

people as i die to

23:59

their children And

24:01

if you are unlucky enough

24:03

not to have well-off

24:05

parents, I mean, that's going to

24:08

feel pretty rotten. Yeah. Yeah. And

24:10

it's entirely random. I mean, it's also things like, are

24:13

you an only child with well-off parents or

24:15

are you one of six with well-off parents?

24:19

Selling off the family home and splitting it five or six ways

24:21

is going to make a big difference compared to

24:23

whether you get all of that into generational

24:25

wealth. And none of this is earned and none

24:28

of this encourages entrepreneurialism,

24:30

productivity, all the kind

24:32

of things we want to see in a

24:34

healthy economy. I think at this point, a cheerful

24:37

note, let's go to a break. Welcome

24:43

back to the Rest is Money with me,

24:45

Robert Peston. Startlingly

24:47

Tim half-earth and run away. So

24:50

I thought we might have a

24:52

chat that flows from

24:54

a special podcast we did

24:56

comparatively recently about the crisis in the

24:58

water industry and in particular the financial

25:01

mess that Thames Water is in. One

25:03

of the points I made is that

25:05

I didn't personally believe

25:07

that water should ever have

25:09

been privatized. Part of

25:12

the reason for that is that I

25:14

think it is a natural monopoly and

25:17

that privatization only really works when you've

25:19

got the scope for competition. Now

25:22

Robert King says, and this

25:24

is a probably intelligent point, he said, why

25:27

isn't gas a monopoly?

25:30

And the short answer to that

25:33

is even though

25:35

gas and water

25:37

rely on pipes

25:40

and anything that has

25:42

an infrastructure element to

25:44

it obviously has monopolistic

25:46

qualities because in practice

25:48

they'll only be a single owner

25:50

of a network of pipes. The

25:53

difference between gas and water is

25:56

there is a global market in

25:58

gas. The

26:00

buy gas from different suppliers

26:02

at different prices you could

26:05

buy on the spot market.

26:07

You could make a bet,

26:09

buy gas for delivery and

26:11

a year or two time

26:14

you can heads and that

26:16

allows buyers of gas to

26:18

compete with each other and

26:20

solve the gas through those

26:23

pipes in competition with each

26:25

other in a way that's

26:27

not possible with water because.

26:30

There is. No. Market or

26:32

is not of the that. there was

26:34

overseas market in bottled water but there

26:36

isn't a markets in the note of

26:38

us reservoirs of water the guys who

26:40

are pipe so in that sense it

26:42

is. the structure is just very different.

26:44

I do remember I said the nineties

26:47

talking to you know the sort of

26:49

brainiacs at the treasury with her in

26:51

favor of privatization of that. They hope

26:53

that one day that would be a

26:55

market him more sir in the way

26:57

that there is for gas and electricity

26:59

but it has never materialized. Ah yeah

27:02

what we've ever gone is a suction

27:04

water industry that it only works if

27:06

regulation is is any good and quite

27:09

frankly I think in recent is that

27:11

regulation has been lousy. That was a

27:13

your thoughts about which services work better

27:15

or worse when privatized. Here is such

27:18

an interesting question and people do tend

27:20

to just was auto ideology my obviously

27:22

we should nationalized them or obviously the

27:25

private sector will do it better myself.

27:27

Look around the world turns out will

27:29

be a little bit more complicated. Than

27:31

that I think in addition to the

27:34

police you've made Robert about gas vs.

27:36

water. Guess it's just easier to regulate

27:38

was it seems he said meets the

27:40

water regulators have made him look difficult

27:42

to regulate Sports with water you've got

27:44

people semi environmental issues as the question

27:46

of discharge what you do with is

27:49

the sewage storage of water. gas just

27:51

seems to be an uneasy a business

27:53

or the That said there was a.

27:55

Wonderful! Offshore as storage

27:58

facility The Ruff. Storage

28:00

facility that we closed rather but

28:02

I think have British Gas or

28:05

Centrica whatever the hell is shut

28:07

down shortly before gas prices spiked

28:09

when Russia invaded Ukraine. So either

28:11

it's possible to make mistakes in

28:14

gas as well. but it is

28:16

a simpler problem he just says

28:18

you, that's all of these utilities

28:21

are in a sense much more

28:23

susceptible Serb. not any regulators decisions

28:25

but government decisions and therefore does

28:27

get us back to this whole

28:30

question. Of do we really

28:32

believe. That. Privatization.

28:35

In. All cases. Delivers

28:38

benefits to consumers and the air. The

28:40

obvious answer is no a wig So

28:42

much better assess competitions if you look

28:44

for example at the privatization of British

28:46

Telecom which at the time you much

28:49

said well this looks a little bit

28:51

like and monopoly right? There were only

28:53

so many telephone wires and only one

28:55

company can own the telephone was splashy

28:57

that privatization really unlocked the you to

29:00

the coming potential of mobile telephony. We

29:02

should not be little bit solve Bt

29:04

that require regulation on that because they

29:06

have a huge network. In the ground

29:08

of was and fiber and all the

29:11

rest of it. So there's a network

29:13

element the required for so far as

29:15

you say, it is an industry where

29:17

innovation has created enormous competition. Absolutely One

29:19

other example I find interesting and and

29:21

I'm no expert this is really just

29:23

a based on on com personally periods

29:25

and asking a few terrorists questions while

29:28

traveling. but German railways? Let's think of

29:30

the Germans and staff. You know they're

29:32

on top of everything. They're brilliant. Everything

29:34

we have this site inferiority complex. I

29:36

love Germany, but the. Children Railways of

29:38

a mess and my understanding I think Toy

29:40

Chip on his own by the gym government

29:43

could be wrong about that. The sent dramatically

29:45

under funded, the infrastructure is under funded and

29:47

it's all falling apart in contrast Japanese my

29:50

which on and legendarily our astonishing. I was

29:52

once in in a Japanese city and a

29:54

train with two minutes late and the person

29:56

I was with waiting for the train was

29:59

convinced that. Try must have come

30:01

up with a light rail service metro

30:03

rail service. He was convinced the same

30:05

must have come and gone and with

30:07

didn't been so intently talking to each

30:09

other that we'd missed it. Couldn't conceive

30:11

that he could possibly be and have

30:13

been stupid estate and was genuinely satan

30:15

when it was a Japanese Railways that

30:17

privately owned since I these or private

30:19

companies February. Interesting structure that I have

30:21

yet to fully understand. The point is

30:23

it's very easy to adopt an ideological

30:25

perspective or we should prioritize. you should

30:27

nationalized at see that the local institutional

30:30

details. History, tradition, culture. they all

30:32

matter perhaps more than we economists

30:34

like to think of. Very fortunately

30:36

the trains that I came to

30:38

the studio on was delayed by

30:40

twenty minutes, but the previous train

30:42

twenty minutes earlier was also delayed

30:44

by twenty minutes. So I was.

30:46

My journey was completely uninterrupted and

30:48

only delayed on paper for this

30:50

is a great metaphor for this

30:52

country I think we do some

30:54

our model for it's now we

30:56

might just very brief seekers as

30:58

connected Issue: Nick Floyd. Says

31:00

themselves as accountable to several stakeholders

31:02

and they stakeholders to which is

31:04

is accountable all consumers, regulators, government

31:06

of course shelled as he simply

31:08

says, why not? Sums a business

31:11

like Thames Water by borrowing rather

31:13

than issue says. I mean one

31:15

recess topical is because their shelters

31:17

are refusing at the moment. Stump

31:19

up more money. The Thames water,

31:21

which is why people think it

31:23

might get past that has to

31:25

be nationalized. I mean the simple

31:27

answer is, financial structure is very.

31:30

between companies are are times when a

31:32

bit more debt is appropriate ice in

31:34

the case of these water companies because

31:36

their earnings are supposed to be reliable

31:39

that they tend to have a same

31:41

way more debt than other sorts of

31:43

restating companies where the earnings are more

31:45

volatiles the point about equity to put

31:47

too much as it also the neck

31:50

is simply that you need a cushion

31:52

of money that can protect you against

31:54

shocks the point about shares his daddy's

31:56

money at risk that you need in

31:59

all businesses to absorb the bad

32:01

times. The problem with relying

32:03

too much on debt is

32:06

when a lender faces losses,

32:08

they have the right to

32:10

simply take control of a

32:12

business, wind it up and close it

32:14

down. And the thing about shares and

32:17

shareholders is shareholders get the

32:19

upside when things are going incredibly well,

32:21

but the corollary of getting the upside

32:23

is they are there to absorb the

32:26

losses when things go badly and they

32:28

prevent a company from going bust

32:30

and being wound up. So in answer to

32:32

Nick, it would not be a great idea

32:34

even for a business as reliable

32:37

a flow of earning as Thames

32:39

Water to have no equity whatsoever, unless that

32:41

is, get back to our original point, it

32:43

were owned by the government because the government

32:45

is there to absorb all losses in the

32:47

case of nationalized

32:49

businesses. Another way to put

32:52

what you've just said Robert is that if

32:54

a company is funded by mostly by debt,

32:56

it's more likely to go bankrupt. If it's

32:58

funded mostly by equity, it's less likely

33:01

to go bankrupt because fundamentally, when you

33:03

borrow money as debt, you're promising to

33:05

pay a particular amount at a particular

33:07

time. And if you don't, you could

33:09

be forced into bankruptcy. Whereas with equity,

33:11

you're just promising to pay shareholders. Well,

33:13

whatever profits happen to be available,

33:15

no particular amount, no particular

33:17

time. And that is a

33:20

structure that is more robust, which is why

33:22

during the banking crisis, we were talking to

33:24

all these orphans who I think were quite

33:26

right, who were saying the banks should have

33:28

raised more money from shareholders and less money from

33:32

debt. Now let's get on

33:34

to a subject that

33:36

always gets people really excited. I don't

33:38

know if you've noticed this, but whenever

33:40

I go around the country and give

33:42

talks to people, we always get on

33:45

to, there's always somebody in the room

33:47

who's obsessed with something called modern monetary

33:49

theory. And the people who

33:51

believe in modern monetary theory think that

33:54

it is a theory that if

33:56

put into practice will make all of

33:58

us richer forever. So

34:00

the question from Ian King is, do

34:03

you think any British political party would

34:05

ever consider modern monetary theory as a

34:07

policy to follow? What do you think?

34:09

By the way, send all your complaints

34:11

about what I'm about to say to

34:13

Robert. Don't email me. I've had all

34:15

the emails about this. Probably

34:18

not. Worth asking what difference would

34:20

it make if a party did

34:22

adopt modern monetary theory? The basic

34:24

idea, I hope I'm not

34:27

oversimplifying, I would try to do it

34:29

justice. The basic idea is when

34:31

you think about the economy, we think about governments have

34:33

to borrow money and then they have to pay the

34:35

money back or they have to pay interest on the

34:37

debt if they don't pay it back. They

34:40

fund their spending by collecting taxes or by

34:42

borrowing. That's our framework. Modern monetary theorists say,

34:44

well, actually there's a different way to think

34:46

about it. I think it's true. There is

34:48

a different way to think about it. You

34:50

can just forget for a moment. Forget taxes,

34:53

forget debt, forget all of that and just

34:55

say, look, the economy is a whole bunch

34:57

of people doing things. It's your people with

34:59

skills, there's capital, there's factories, there's

35:01

buildings, there's all of this stuff and

35:03

the economy can produce a certain amount

35:05

of output. Sometimes there's slack in the

35:08

economy. It's underutilized. At that point, you

35:10

need to do something to engage those

35:12

slack resources. Modern monetary theory basically

35:14

says, look, if there's slack in the economy,

35:16

you could just print money. They have a

35:18

more clever way of doing it, but fundamentally

35:20

you could just print money and that will

35:22

bring those slack resources online. Print money, employ

35:24

the people who are unemployed, you know, occupy

35:26

those factories, get them back to work, all

35:28

of that kind of thing. That's

35:30

basically true. There's all kinds of ways you

35:33

can account for it. Modern monetary

35:35

theorists are right about that. The trouble is,

35:37

it only really is a radical idea if

35:39

there's a lot of slack in the economy.

35:42

Right now, there's no evidence of any slack

35:44

in the economy. We've got very high levels

35:46

of employment. We'll be more precise

35:48

about that. We've got very low levels of

35:50

unemployment. We've got high levels of inflation. So

35:52

no matter how you account for it, whether

35:54

you do some fancy modern monetary theory policy

35:57

or whatever, there's not a lot of slack in

35:59

the economy. out there. And I think

36:01

that the advantage is that the modern

36:03

monetary theorists say that they can offer

36:05

only work when the economy is running

36:07

with a lot of slack. Why do

36:09

you think, because this is the bit

36:11

that always confuses me about some proponents

36:13

of modern monetary theory, I

36:16

would not be somebody who says

36:18

that inflation is wholly a

36:20

monetary phenomenon. I do think,

36:22

however, that there is

36:24

always a monetary element to inflation.

36:26

The more money there is in

36:29

the economy relative to a certain

36:31

level of output, the

36:33

cheaper, in a sense, that money

36:35

is, in which case the higher

36:37

prices will be. And that's

36:40

just sort of basic. But

36:42

what I don't understand about the proponents, genuine,

36:44

modern monetary theory is quite often they say

36:46

in a period of inflation, and

36:49

they did say that in the recent period of inflation,

36:51

there's no problem with creating a lot more money it

36:54

won't make inflation worse. And that just feels

36:56

a very odd thing to say, but do

36:58

you have any understanding of why they say

37:00

that? No, I don't understand why that would

37:02

be true. And so maybe I am blameworthy.

37:05

I don't understand the theory to that extent.

37:07

I certainly understand how printing money would work

37:09

in a slum. I could certainly understand

37:11

how if George Osborne had

37:13

had a modern monetary theorists whispering

37:15

in his ear in 2010, 2011,

37:18

we might well have had better economic policy

37:20

back then. But right now, I would have

37:22

thought that the modern monetary theorists would be

37:24

saying really exactly what conventional economists would be

37:27

saying, which is you need to be very

37:29

careful of stoking more inflation. And I'm surprised

37:31

to hear that they don't. I mean, one

37:33

of the things that I think is quite

37:35

interesting in the case of recent

37:37

economic history, we sort of started

37:39

talking about how I think we

37:42

first met during the financial crisis. And

37:44

I remember immediately, well,

37:47

as it looked like the financial crisis was going

37:49

to lead us into a

37:51

very serious slump, and then we became

37:53

it became clear the economy

37:56

was going to be stagnating for years and

37:58

years, some of that as a result. of

38:00

that banking shock, some

38:02

of it as a result of austerity.

38:05

We did see at that

38:08

point the beginning of a debate

38:10

about this concept called helicopter

38:12

money and there were perfectly serious people,

38:14

remember talking to a boat you'll know

38:16

as well called Adair Turner who was

38:18

one of the regulators at the time

38:20

and he was talking publicly about the

38:22

idea of essentially whether the Bank

38:25

of England should simply create a ton

38:27

of money and it should

38:29

just be distributed to people in some

38:31

shape or form or given to the

38:33

government to fund public service spending. Either

38:36

way it would be pure money creation

38:38

of the sort that we have just

38:41

discussed. We didn't get that. What

38:43

we did get was quantitative easing and

38:45

quantitative easing is related but not quite

38:48

the same thing. It is the Bank

38:50

of England creating very significant

38:52

amounts of new money which started

38:54

after the financial crisis, started quantitative

38:56

easing after the financial crisis and

38:58

then buying government debt that did

39:01

increase the supply of money but

39:03

it didn't have quite the same

39:06

stimulating effect because the Bank of

39:08

England was not writing off the

39:10

government debt. The

39:13

government was still on the hook to

39:15

pay off all those hundreds of billions

39:17

of pounds. One of the things

39:19

since the start of QE that has been debated

39:21

a lot is whether it

39:23

would have been or would still be

39:25

rational to write off the debt and

39:27

just have this pure money creation rather

39:31

than insist that this is still a

39:34

real debt that the government has to

39:36

repay. Again, I just wondered if you

39:38

had thoughts about any of this. One

39:42

economist said, it's a bit like you've got this

39:44

giant vacuum cleaner that you can use to hoover

39:47

up all the money. You've thrown all the money

39:49

out of a helicopter and then you can hoover

39:51

it up with this giant vacuum cleaner. Cancelling the

39:53

government debt is basically destroying the hoover. You

39:56

can throw the money into the economy but you can't take it out again. that

40:00

was risky. But sometimes you need to take policy

40:02

risks, sometimes you need to tie your own hands

40:04

and say, look, we're cancelling this, we can't actually

40:06

go back. Maybe that would have been

40:09

a bit more stimulative. So I suppose the question is,

40:11

when I talked to former Governor Bank

40:14

of England, something like Mervyn King, an

40:17

older generation of economists, still

40:19

felt not only scarred

40:21

by the inflation that

40:23

this country went through in the

40:26

60s and 70s, but equally, people

40:29

would talk openly about what they

40:31

felt was the risk of a sort

40:33

of German style hyperinflation. And we

40:35

already haven't seen anything like

40:37

that as a result of QE, but do you think

40:39

that was a real risk? I don't think so. It

40:41

never struck me as very plausible given how what

40:44

stress the banking system was under printing

40:46

a bit more money didn't seem like a

40:48

risk to me. I guess fundamentally, there are

40:51

two fears that different sides of

40:53

this debate have. And I think the fears are

40:55

well justified on both sides. So there is a

40:57

fear, the whole kind of modern monetary thing or

40:59

the helicopter money thing or all this idea that

41:02

you know, actually, maybe there is

41:04

a magic money tree. There's some

41:06

real truth behind that. But there's always

41:08

a risk that governments lose their discipline.

41:11

They see it as an easy way out,

41:13

they print money, and then you've got growing

41:15

inflation and the whole thing is Weimar Germany,

41:17

the whole thing becomes a mess. That's

41:19

always the risk if you give politicians

41:21

that temptation. Then on the other side

41:23

of the debate, there's this risk that

41:25

the Treasury is just too much a

41:28

slave to the debt figures and

41:30

doesn't think imaginatively enough about

41:32

ways of spending money to stimulate the

41:34

economy to increase productive potential. And that's

41:36

a risk too. And at different points

41:39

of British economic history and different points

41:41

of world economic history, different risks have

41:43

been more salient. But they're both fair,

41:45

they're both potential policy errors. And

41:47

you know, we're just trying to steer a middle way. So we've

41:49

got time for one more question. This is from Peter.

41:53

And it's about tariffs. And

41:56

he asks how much of an impact will US

41:58

tariffs have. So what

42:01

we've seen from Biden is

42:04

the introduction of really very

42:06

significant tariffs on imports from

42:08

China, everything from electric vehicles

42:10

through the semiconductors, through to

42:13

solar panels. I mean it's a great raft

42:15

of goods worth billions and billions and billions

42:17

every year. I suppose it sort

42:19

of brings us on to this question about when

42:22

there are restrictions on trade, when

42:24

you put taxes on trade, who

42:27

suffers? Is it the seller of

42:29

those goods or is it the

42:31

buyer of those goods? So the way

42:33

to think about this is to imagine

42:36

that instead of China, you just have

42:38

this great big factory on the American

42:40

coast making all of these amazing cheap

42:43

EVs, semiconductors, digging up all these rare

42:45

earth metals, producing solar cells and so

42:47

on. And you've got this amazing factory

42:50

that's producing all this fantastic

42:52

stuff and it's great

42:54

for the American consumer because they

42:56

just, they can just go take

42:58

their dollars to the factory, buy

43:01

all this stuff. And then one

43:03

day an intrepid investigative reporter, Robert

43:05

Peston for example, breaks into the factory

43:08

and reveals to a shocked world that

43:10

there is no factory there. It's just

43:12

docks and all that's happening is ships

43:14

are coming from China and bringing this

43:16

stuff. Now we think very

43:18

differently about the stuff being made in

43:20

China versus the stuff being made in

43:22

a US factory full of robots. But

43:24

fundamentally the economics are very similar to

43:26

the stuff being made in a factory

43:29

full of robots on the coast of

43:31

California versus the stuff being made in

43:33

China. And the impact of the tariffs,

43:36

broadly speaking, is going to be to

43:38

make stuff more expensive for American consumers

43:40

at the same time. And that makes

43:42

American consumers poorer. Makes them poorer.

43:44

At the same time, it's very good for

43:46

American producers of EVs, anybody who's trying to

43:49

make this stuff who's protected

43:51

from a Chinese competition is going

43:53

to do well. Now, the classic

43:55

economic models basically say overall this

43:57

is a loss. So America is

44:00

poorer because of these tariffs. In

44:03

reality, there's all kinds of other stuff going on. One

44:05

of the things that's going on is politics.

44:07

These tariffs are going to make Joe Biden

44:10

more likely to be reelected. Donald Trump's attack

44:12

on them should have happened sooner. There should

44:14

be more. Both sides of the political aisle

44:17

in the US want these tariffs. This is

44:19

basically nakedly political on the part of the

44:21

Biden administration. In the medium

44:23

term, it's bad news for the environment

44:25

because you just get fewer electric vehicles,

44:27

more expensive electric vehicles in the US.

44:29

In the long term, who knows? There

44:31

is an argument. I don't think it's

44:34

an absurd argument. There is an argument

44:36

that these tariffs will protect a nascent

44:38

American industry. America is still switching over

44:40

to electric vehicles. They haven't quite got

44:42

there yet, despite the market leader, Tesla.

44:44

They need to produce solar panels. They

44:46

need to produce all of these green

44:48

goods. If you let all

44:50

this cheap competition from China, which has heavily

44:53

subsidized all this stuff, if you let that

44:55

flood in, it'll destroy all these American industries

44:57

before they've really got off the ground. In

44:59

the long run, America's worse off. The whole

45:01

world's worse off. I wonder. That

45:04

might be true. Obviously, it's also pretty

45:06

self-serving for all of these domestic US

45:08

industries. It just sort of gets back

45:10

to the origins of modern economics. Modern

45:12

economics is founded on Smith and Ricardo.

45:15

They would say that what America is

45:17

doing is really bad for America and

45:19

really bad for prosperity everywhere. I suppose

45:23

what I would say to them, and doubtless

45:25

they will be in this room one of

45:27

these days on the rest of his money,

45:29

what I would say is you can't take

45:31

politics out of this. For

45:35

me, the really interesting question is we did

45:38

live through decades of

45:41

saying globalization is a good thing.

45:43

It was raising living standards all

45:46

over the world. Actually, the numbers

45:48

lifted out of poverty in China

45:50

in particular was astonishing. I think

45:52

we sort of hoped that that

45:54

would be associated, that globalization would

45:57

be associated with democracy.

46:00

policy, also taking greater

46:02

root all over the

46:04

place, in particular in China. And

46:07

therefore we thought prosperity would be

46:10

associated with what we think of

46:12

in our liberal economies as progress.

46:14

But it hasn't been. Precisely

46:17

the reverse has happened in China. It's

46:19

become a much more autocratic state. And

46:22

it seems to me therefore simply

46:24

turning a blind eye, which we

46:26

did for years, to the enormous

46:28

subsidies that were going into Chinese

46:30

industries, the way that they were

46:33

deliberately depressing the value

46:35

of their currency to make

46:37

their exports cheaper was

46:40

a bit naive. I should always take perspective where we

46:42

started. There is more to our

46:44

security than just our short-term living standards.

46:46

Yes, our living standards improved for

46:48

a period as a result of that globalization.

46:51

But arguably the world is a much

46:53

more dangerous place, having a

46:56

very powerful, autocratic,

46:59

incredibly now well-resourced China.

47:01

Yeah. It's hard

47:03

to know what the alternative would have been

47:05

and how things would have played out. I'm

47:08

not quite as pessimistic as you, Robert, about the progress

47:10

of democracy. Clearly things in China

47:12

are pretty frightening. On the other hand, they were

47:14

also pretty frightening in the early 1980s, the late

47:16

1970s, before all

47:19

of this started. North Korea has

47:21

made wonderful progress towards not

47:23

only richer but vastly more democratic than

47:26

it was in the 1970s. And

47:28

North Korea, which is cut off from

47:30

democracy, isn't. Eastern Europe has

47:32

made – there are some exceptions, but it's

47:34

made amazing progress towards freedom and democracy. So

47:36

there are definitely some dark spots, but we

47:38

shouldn't forget the bright spots too as to

47:41

how much of any of this is

47:43

connected to the process of globalization. I

47:46

wish I fully understood. What I do

47:48

know is it's always easier when you're making

47:50

an economic choice to blame

47:52

the foreigner than to spend

47:54

domestic money. Biden's

47:56

doing both. He's spending a lot of money

47:59

boosting. The U S A good

48:01

green industries try to create set up

48:03

the screen that that year these green

48:05

technology hubs and build or eve ease

48:07

but he's also. Blaming. The Chinese

48:09

and and. A kind of wish

48:11

he was. Circus. More on the

48:13

spending money and less on the layman the

48:16

Chinese. But as you say, politics is, politics

48:18

is and isn't. That seems to be a

48:20

good moment to say thank you very much.

48:22

Indeed, that was terrific. Ah much as I

48:24

had. I hope you're happy back Robert This

48:26

has been such fun! Thank you so much

48:29

for asking me. You'll. Definitely. I.

48:31

We've had five episodes of Liz Truss.

48:33

Say what episode of Tim Harford is

48:35

simply not enough? Absolutely. I just remind

48:38

us. but you're amazing. Book us yes,

48:40

Cautionary Tales with Tim Harford wherever you

48:42

get your podcasts and more or less

48:45

his back on the Bbc very shortly

48:47

as well. So said goodbye

48:49

for me to buy for me

48:51

and importantly step will be back

48:53

for our next episode. Thank goodness

48:55

for the rest is money!

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features